52 pages • 1 hour read
A modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.
Summary
Background
Chapter Summaries & Analyses
Key Figures
Themes
Index of Terms
Important Quotes
Essay Topics
Tools
Chapter 4 is divided into two parts: The first explores IMF policies that have led to the 1997 economic depression, and the second underlines the ineffectiveness of the IMF’s response to alleviate the depression.
Stiglitz first advances the idea that the IMF’s push for rapid financial and capital market liberalization was at the core of the Thai baht collapse and subsequent global economic depression in 1997. The crisis is the result of a too quick and too little regulated financial market liberalization policy, encouraged by the IMF and the US Treasury. Both pushed for full capital account liberalization in East Asia, arguing it would help the region grow even faster, despite knowing that the region did not need additional capital due to its high savings rate.
Stiglitz cites Korea as a perfect example of this: The US Treasury presented Korea’s potential capital market liberalization as an event of national significance for the US, despite the National Economic Council’s disagreement. In the end, the deal was concluded behind closed doors and Korea was forced to deregulate its financial market. On top of being highly undemocratic, this decision was imposed on Korea, which was afraid that refusal would make it look unreliable to foreign investment. Despite the US Treasury and the IMF’s insistence, these deregulatory policies have little evidence of actually promoting growth.
Subsequently, however, the IMF also did not help mitigate the effects of the crisis in Thailand. It instead imposed stringent conditions on providing funds, including forcing countries to maintain high interest rates, which failed to curtail the recession in Asia and precipitated a fall in exchange rates that would end up affecting the entire region.
Stiglitz holds the IMF accountable for misdiagnosing the causes of the crisis. Based on this faulty analysis, it proposed inadequate solutions to the problem. First, it attempted to curb demand during a recession, when there is already insufficient demand, under the guise of balancing budgets. However, Keynesian economics argues that to help mitigate a recession, governments or regulatory infrastructures must find ways to stimulate demand. This can be done through expanding fiscal policy, but the IMF instead pursued austere budget balancing that discourages investment and spending. Second, it raised interest rates when firms had high levels of indebtedness, which forced many into bankruptcy and increased unemployment rates.
Additionally, the IMF failed to recognize that imposing austere fiscal policies onto one country affects neighboring countries as well. To bolster their own economy, countries reduce exports to keep their resources for domestic consumption. To do this, they impose tariffs on foreign products and devalue their own currency, reducing the cost of their own goods compared to imports. However, these protectionist policies also affect neighboring countries, which see a reduction in their exports, thereby causing the spread of the economic depression. The IMF exacerbated this process by asking countries to cut back on imports in order to balance their budgets. As a result, the IMF’s policies have had the opposite effect of its original mission.
Although the IMF was later criticized for its East Asian policies, this only served to further lower confidence in foreign investment in the region. Stiglitz notably describes the IMF as having become part of the problem.
The rest of this chapter is dedicated to analyzing why IMF policies could not curtail the spread nor alleviate the depth of the 1997 financial crisis. Stiglitz first advances the argument that the IMF pushed for a “restructuring” of the financial market in East Asia instead of providing funds to assist necessary expenditure in the region. In Keynesian terms, its policies encouraged a shrinking rather than an expansion of aggregate demand. Its reasoning is simple: It was more concerned with paying back investors than sustaining growth in Asia.
The IMF exacerbated the economic recession by separating healthy from sick banks and shutting down the latter, therefore forcing the rest to quickly meet the capital adequacy ratio—determined by balancing their available capital to their outstanding loans and assets. This policy works when one single bank operates poorly due to mismanagement. It is disastrous in situations where most banks are in trouble due to greater macroeconomic forces.
Businesses lose access to credit and are forced to shut down if they do not find an alternative bank from which to borrow. Unemployment rates increase and production decreases. When industries are forced to shut down, the process cannot easily be reversed. Stiglitz underlines this truth by contrasting South Korea with Indonesia. The former recovered quicker because it recapitalized its banks and ignored the IMF’s advice. In contrast, Indonesia was plunged into a longer-term recession.
The IMF pushed for real restructuring rather than financial restructuring: It asked governments to force firms to reorganize their assets and production when it should have instead asked governments to settle the issue of ownership first, which would have given firms a better chance of reentering credit markets. When a large number of firms are unsure of whether shareholders or current CEOs own the company, management tends to sell assets, forcing companies further into bankruptcy and preventing any chance of recovery.
Most egregiously, the IMF paid $23 billion to bail out creditors while shrinking aid to help the poor, despite Stiglitz warning that this would invite political upheaval. Even beyond the humanitarian argument, Stiglitz believes this decision to be simply bad economics, as poor political stability drives capital out and frays confidence. After riots broke out in Indonesia, the IMF reversed its policies and resumed food subsidies. However, the damage was already done, as people began to question why the funds were contracted when they were perfectly affordable. Workers who saw their wages cut by a quarter knew the economy was stalled from where it could have been, had the crisis been mitigated.
Malaysia and China did not follow IMF programs and grew rapidly compared to other East Asian countries who did. They practiced capital control to prevent having to increase interest rates, thus stalling a large economic recession and allowing firms to stay afloat. This expansionary fiscal and monetary policy brought a certain degree of economic stability, which in turn reinstated confidence in the eye of foreign investors. In contrast to these two countries, Thailand followed the IMF’s orders and still remained in recession three years later.
The IMF now admits its response and policies were too austere, but it still does not recognize that it has made mistakes in its monetary policy. It imposed “astronomically” high interest rates that stunted spending (130). It forced increases of more than 25% at the same time as the Clinton administration worried about the negative effects of a 0.5% increase in domestic interest. It did so under the pretext that high interest rates would incentivize payback and therefore help restore market confidence. However, in a region where firms are leveraged and indebted, an increase in interest rate could spell bankruptcy, which in turn affects banks, contracting both aggregate demand and supply.
When Stiglitz asked the IMF to change its policies, it adopted a wait-and-see attitude. When Japan proposed to create an Asian Monetary Fund to redress the economic situation in the region, it was harshly turned down by the IMF and the US Treasury, who wanted to maintain a monopoly in their own domain.
In sum, Stiglitz demonstrates in this chapter that hubris and the Western financial community’s dogged pursuit of a liberal market ideology caused the IMF to misdiagnose and mistreat the 1997 crisis. Additionally, he provides deeper economic analysis of the IMF’s actions. Chapter 4, along with Chapter 5, most clearly touches upon the first of the three themes of this guide: The Failures of Market Fundamentalism and IMF Policy. Stiglitz’s discontent with market fundamentalism and with its ineffectiveness is not only because it is an ideological rather than practical pursuit but also because it is a flawed and disproven economic model. Although not all of its premises are wrong—Stiglitz does believe in privatization and liberalization—its conclusion, that markets are self-regulatory, has had devastating effects when put into practice by the IMF.
This dogged pursuit of ideology has disincentivized the IMF from developing alternate policies, even after the 1997 crisis. It blinded the Fund to economic indices that affect growth, including employment rates, but that are not valued by the model. In other words, had the Fund paid attention to its mistakes, it would have realized that economic downturns are best resolved by pursuing expansionary monetary and fiscal policies.
This section uses post-Communist Russia as a case example of the IMF prioritizing the defense of free-market ideology over helping grow standards of living. This bias has caused it to focus on macro statistics and such quantitative data as the only indicators of a country’s economic well-being while disregarding social indices, or The Importance of Social Capital, such as unemployment rate or poverty rate, by dismissing them as unimportant or irrelevant. Chapter 5 significantly expands on the idea that trickle-down economics is an exercise in blind faith. For the first time, Stiglitz explicitly details why social capital is necessary for economic stability and the overall improvement of living standards.
The IMF regarded the restructuring of the Russian economy as a simple case of implementing textbook economics rather than a restructuring of the whole society. However, transitioning from a communist to a market economy requires not only ideological change but also the establishment of institutional infrastructures such as banks and firms, the training of entrepreneurship, and a robust regulatory legal system. For example, banks under the Soviet regime only lent money when the government allowed them and did not participate in investment. Farmers were handed seeds, and workers were provided housing. Transitioning to a market economy entails the creation of a series of new institutional infrastructures that helps people ease into an entirely new lifestyle.
Instead, the IMF rushed the transition, afraid that people would wish to revert back to communism if it was too slow. This tactic, defended by the US Treasury and the IMF, was dubbed “shock therapy” (141). They pushed for rapid liberalization, privatization, and stabilization. The result was an overnight freeing of prices on goods in 1992, causing hyperinflation and forcing the IMF to remedy this macroinstability by raising interest rates. Privatization, in turn, could not happen smoothly because hyperinflation obliterated the Russian people’s savings, preventing them from being able to purchase newly privatized enterprises. Likewise, high interest rates hampered entrepreneurs from revitalizing firms, even when they could purchase them. As a result, Russia saw a loss in gross domestic product greater than what it suffered during World War II.
The 1997 Asian crisis also negatively impacted the Russian economy by causing the price of oil—a natural resource that provided Russia with a stable source of capital—to plummet due to a lack of demand. Oligarchs and corrupt officials began converting their ruble into US dollars, sending away billions in foreign banks and causing an outflow of capital. The IMF decided to gather bailout money rather than push for reform, in spite of knowing the rampant corruption that existed in Russia, because it wished to maintain the current exchange rate, with an overvalued ruble, so that paybacks to foreign lenders would be easier. The IMF also pushed the World Bank to lend $6 billion to complement the IMF’s own $11.2 billion in bailout money.
Stiglitz was deeply weary of the IMF’s policies, so he and the team at the World Bank instead negotiated to pay the sum in installments, accurately predicting that there would be a program failure very soon. Indeed, oligarchs and corrupt officials in Russia sent IMF bailout money to their overseas banks and announced in January 1999 a suspension of payments, which devalued the ruble by more than 45% in six months. This in turn caused a global financial crisis felt across the world, the brunt of which was shouldered not by the IMF but by ordinary taxpayers. The IMF’s policies caused a decrease in standard of living in Russia in 2000 compared to what it was in 1989. Inflation wiped out the middle class and worsened inequality.
This chapter is a perfect example of how ideology is the deciding factor that influences the IMF’s policy. It illustrates The Failures of Market Fundamentalism and IMF Policy: It does not account for the state and structure of society. Instead, it takes for granted that infrastructures are in place to facilitate the operation of free markets. It assumes that unemployment does not matter as long as macroeconomic statistics are in balance. It presumes that corruption does not exist, competition is perfect, information is distributed, and wealth will always trickle down. Russia proves that none of this is guaranteed in practice without adequate regulatory measures.
Stiglitz argues that the country is resource-rich and had the means to recover from economic depression if it underwent internal reform. In other words, its recovery was not dependent on international aid. In the end, the IMF’s policies caused an erosion of “social capital,” defined as the underlying forces that hold a society together. Privatization done wrong allowed for rampant corruption and broke people’s confidence in the government, market economies, and democratic process. The IMF focused on macroeconomic balancing and overlooked issues of inequality and poverty. Its decision-making aligns with the political goals of the Clinton administration—to maintain Boris Yeltsin in power—rather than the well-being of the Russian people.
In this section, Stiglitz argues that the economically disastrous policies of the IMF are best understood if the organization is viewed as a political institution with an ideology that aligns with that of the US Treasury. In other words, they lend Funds to maintain their ideology rather than balance the global economy. They care more to pay back foreign investors than help the livelihoods of the Russian people.
For example, many Russian ex-Communist officials were pragmatists at heart, rather than true ideological hard-liners, and Stiglitz believes their political leaning would align with that of American New Dealers. Nevertheless, the Clinton administration mistrusted them all on an ideological basis, electing only to work with those who had run business-like institutions for the regime, without realizing these people were often more interested in enriching themselves than creating a true market economy for Russia.
Stuck between domestic corruption and unreasonable IMF and US Treasury demands, the Russian government turned to the World Bank and invited Stiglitz for an independent discussion, free of the IMF and the US Treasury’s influence. Stiglitz was surprised to see the extent of debate within Russia: He comments that its capacity to follow democratic processes puts the opaque nature of the IMF and the US Treasury to shame.
This chapter serves to illustrate that long-term growth policies are ultimately more beneficial to all parties than the IMF and US Treasury’s hunger for short-term rewards. The author concludes that the US’s long-term goal of fighting communism would have been better served had the IMF broadly supported democratic initiatives in Russia, rather than particular leaders. In other words, the narrow pursuit of ideology is rarely useful in promoting sustained growth.
Stiglitz goes even further: The IMF is hypocritical in its pursuit of ideology. It touts the benefits of free trade but defends US special interests when those freed markets threaten US domestic production. For example, when aluminum prices dropped in 1994 due to a global reduction in demand, the US approved of aluminum producer Paul O’Neil’s decision to create a cartel by artificially reducing output and raising prices. This was done to the detriment of Russia, which could produce aluminum at a lower price than the US and relied on it as one of its major sources of export. Ironically, cartels are illegal in the US domestic market, once again demonstrating the double standard that existed when the US decided to protect its special interests. In an attempt to teach Russian officials about the free-market system, the US actually demonstrated that its practices strayed far from the theory.
Finally, Stiglitz also highlights the importance of transparency throughout this chapter—the free circulation of information—as an essential element in democratic processes. Had the US Treasury allowed for greater debate within the government, the disastrous situation in Russia might have taken higher priority in the eyes of the Clinton administration. This chapter offers a practical example to support the overall theme that ideological fervor and the blind pursuit of market fundamentalism can severely destabilize a country’s economy. It defends this idea by comparing two ex-Communist bloc countries in Eastern Europe with similar economic and political situations at the end of the 1970s, observing that only the one that did not follow IMF rules (Poland) ended up developing significantly better.
Unlock all 52 pages of this Study Guide
Plus, gain access to 9,150+ more expert-written Study Guides.
Including features: